Article Index

 

Articles

Peter Adriaens & Deborah De Lange, Field Structuration Around New Issues: Clean Energy Entrepreneurialism in Emerging Economies (Ross School of Business, Paper No. 1180, 2012), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=2171852.

Abstract (by authors)This research contributes to the literature on emerging industries by examining how an organizational field takes form as a new entrepreneurial venture arises and is legitimized. Clean energy firms face unprecedented challenges, arising in emerging economies where energy infrastructure is inadequate or non-existent. These are local contexts where there are no preexisting related industries, yet the intent is to diffuse renewable energy widely to an extent that it could spur broader local economic development. This research proposes that in the absence of legitimacy-building mimetic, normative and regulative mechanisms, unique types of endorsements legitimize and enable new firms in nascent industries.

Arvind Chaturvedi & Sonu Goyal, Changing Severity of Impediments for Entrepreneurs in India: An Empirical Analysis, 16 Int'l J. Entrepren. & Small Bus. 1 (2012).

Abstract (from journal): One of the key emphasis areas of India's economic reforms has been to promote entrepreneurship. Since the beginning of 1990s, in the last 20 years the economic planning has focused on liberalisation of state's control to enable an entrepreneur to overcome the impediments in setting up enterprises and establishing them. It is generally believed that over the last two decades of reform process the problems faced by start ups have also reduced. This study has been carried out using data gathered through a survey of 136 entrepreneurs based in New Delhi, the capital city of India. The three periods defined for the study of impediments faced by the entrepreneurs in setting up their ventures are: before 1994 (Period I); between 1995 to 2004 (Period II) and 2005 onwards (Period III). Based on the existing frameworks of country institutional profile key impediments for the survey were identified and analysed in the light of India's economic reform process impacting the entrepreneurial activity.

Juan Pablo Couyoumdjian, Who Walks Out? Entrepreneurship in a Global Economy, 32 Int'l Rev. L. & Econ. 158 (2012).

Abstract (from authors): This article examines how entrepreneurs decide in what country to locate their businesses. The quality of a location's institutions, measured by factors such as political security, bureaucracy, and good governance, play an important role this decision.

Ross B. Emmett, Frank H. Knight on the "Entrepreneur Function” in Modern Enterprise, 34 Seattle U. L. Rev. 1139 (2011).

Abstract (from author): Frank Knight’s theory of the entrepreneurial function in modern enterprise is explored in two contexts. The first is the dismissal of the neoclassical theory of business enterprise by Berle and Means in The Modern Corporation and Private Property, and their subsequent call for measures that would ensure corporations acted in the social interest. The second context used to explore Knight’s theory of entrepreneurship is his later arguments regarding the problem of intelligent control in a democratic society. Underlying all of Knight’s work are his concerns about freedom and moral judgment in the midst of uncertainty, with the attendant problems commonly referred to today as the principal-agent problem and moral hazard. Knight argues that the entrepreneur personally absorbs these problems through his responsible direction of the modern enterprise; seen this way, profit is not just the return for bearing the risks of unknown consequences, but specifically for the courage to take up the challenge of organizing productive resources in the face of principal-agent and moral hazard problems. In the latter part of Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit, Knight argues that social functionaries are not entrepreneurs, and hence that democratic action will be plagued by principal-agent and moral hazard problems; a conclusion that much vexed him in his later ruminations on the fate of liberal democratic society. Were the authors to apply Knight’s insights to Berle and Means’ call for social control of the modern corporation, one could turn their argument around and ask: control by whom, for whose interest?

Mirit Eyal-Cohen, Down-Sizing the "Little Guy" Myth in Legal Definitions, 98 Iowa L. Rev. 1041 (2013).

Abstract (by author) What is a “small business” in the eyes of the law? There is not one standard definition. Current legal definitions of a firm's size are inconsistent and over inclusive. They vary from one area of the law to another and within various sections of the same law. They create a skewed picture and result in data distortion that reinforces favoritism toward small entities, as studies on the contribution of small businesses to the economy are greatly dependent on these studies' delineation of the term “small.” In this time of huge deficits and rise in economic inequality, a lot of money is being spent based on the entrenched belief that small firms are the essence of our economy, which is not necessarily true. Therefore, this article argues that the current focus on size in many legal definitions is a waste of both time and money. This article provides a comprehensive survey of legal definitions of small entities and the policy considerations that underlie these delineations. This article concludes that the historical emphasis on magnitude no longer functions effectively. Current legal demarcations concentrated on “smallness” generate undesirable distributional effects, produce inefficient allocation of government resources, and defeat policy considerations of promoting entrepreneurship and economic growth. The recent proposal to integrate the Small Business Administration with other federal commerce and trade agencies into one super pro-business agency is yet one more step toward this proposed shift from a size-centered to a goal-driven approach.

Mirit Eyal-Cohen, Legal Mirrors of Entrepreneurship, 55 B.C. L. Rev. 719 (2014),available at  http://ssrn.com/abstract=2350206.

Abstract (by author): Small businesses are regarded as the engine of the economy. But just what is a "small" business? Depending on where one looks in the law, the definitions vary and they differ from one section to another. Unfortunately, what these various size classifications fail to assess, are the policy considerations and the legislative intent for granting regulatory preferences to small concerns to begin with. 

In the last century, the U.S. government has been cultivating one such policy of fiscal and economic growth. Consequently, Congress and private institutions have been acting to incentivize, support and reward entrepreneurship through the law in order to stimulate the economy. Nevertheless, rather than targeting entrepreneurial businesses directly, the law grants preferences to entities according to their size reflecting an obsolescent mirror of past economies. Today, while most entrepreneurial firms may start small, not all small firms innovate and create new economic value.

This article applies "mirror theory" and proposes a novel legal model that strives to correlate between the design of our legal rules, the goals they set to advance, and the societal trends they reflect. The article suggests replacing the current size-based approach in our laws with a model that measures firms’ entrepreneurial orientation. Unlike the current binary small-or-not standard, this multi-tiered, simple, and flexible model reduces the intrinsic arbitrariness, complexity, and uncertainty in current legal definitions.

Jason R. Fitzsimmons and Evan J. Douglas, Interaction Between Feasibility and Desirability in the Formation of Entrepreneurial Intentions, 26 J. Bus. Venturing 431 (2010).

AbstractThis article examines how the perception of desirability and feasibility determine entrepreneurial intentions, based on a regulatory focus theory.

Stephan F. Gohmann, Institutions, Latent Entrepreneurship, and Self-Employment: An International Comparison, 36 Entrepren. Theory & Prac. 323 (2012).

Abstract (from journal): This paper examines how the institutional environment in 18 countries affects the self-employment decision, as well as the preferences of latent entrepreneurs—individuals who prefer to be self-employed. Latent entrepreneurs fall into two groups, those who are currently self-employed and those who are not—the “truly latent entrepreneurs.” These two groups differ in their responses to changes in the institutional environment. An occupational choice model where institutions affect switching costs informs the empirical model. As institutions such as economic freedom improve, preferences for self-employment increase for both groups, but the effect is greater for those who are currently self-employed.

Magnus Henrekson, Entrepreneurship and Institutions, 28 Comp. Lab. L. & Pol'y J. 717 (2006-2007).

Abstract:  In this paper entrepreneurs are defined as agents who bring about economic change by combining their own effort with other factors of production in search of economic rents. The institutional setup is argued to determine both the supply and direction of entrepreneurial activity. Four key institutions are explored more closely: property rights protection, savings policies, taxation and the regulation of labor markets. Institutions have far-reaching effects on entrepreneurship, and they largely determine whether or not entrepreneurial activity will be socially productive. Due to the responsiveness of entrepreneurship to the institutional setup it is maintained that in-depth analyses of specific institutions are required in order to further our understanding of the determinants of entrepreneurial behavior and the economic effects of entrepreneurship. The paper also demonstrates that it is problematic to use self-employment as an empirical proxy for productive entrepreneurship.

Magnus Henrekson & Tino Sanandaji, Billionaire Entrepreneurs: A Systematic Analysis (IFN, Working Paper No. 959, 2013), available athttp://ssrn.com/abstract=2229197.

Abstract (by authors): The overwhelming majority of self-employed individuals are not entrepreneurial in the Schumpeterian sense. In order to unmistakably identify Schumpeterian entrepreneurs we focus on self-made billionaires (in USD) on Forbes Magazine’s list who became wealthy by founding new firms. In this way the paper identifies 996 billionaire entrepreneurs in over fifty countries in the 1996–2010 period. To the authors' knowledge this is the first systematic cross-country study of billionaire entrepreneurs, an economically important group. The paper demonstrates that the common practice of relying on self-employment and related measures to proxy for entrepreneurship often gives rise to misleading inferences. Interestingly the rate of billionaire entrepreneurs per capita correlates negatively with self-employment rates. Countries with higher income, higher trust, lower taxes, more venture capital investment and lower regulatory burdens have higher entrepreneurship rates but less self-employment.

Steven H. Hobbs, Toward a Theory of Law and Entrepreneurship, 26 Cap. U.L. Rev. 241, 261 (1997)

Abstract: The irresistible urge to strike out on one's own and start an exciting business is part of our American landscape. The idea of entrepreneurship is touted in the popular media, and the popular press publishes plenty of books on the subject. As a discipline, entrepreneurship has flourished in America's schools of business. The possibilities are endless in a world of constantly emerging technologies and shifts from a manufacturing-base economy to a service/information-base economy. While many large corporations are adapting entrepreneurial theories to become more competitive in a global market, the heart of entrepreneurship lies in the creation of small ventures by one person or a small group of individuals.

Darian M. Ibrahim, How Do Start-ups Obtain Their Legal Services?, 2012 Wis. L. Rev. 333 (2012).

Abstract (from author): This Essay is the first to examine, using responses to online surveys, the use of in-house versus outside counsel by rapid-growth start-up companies. It also explores, from the vantage point of the start-up's entrepreneur, some reasons for that choice. The Essay tests several hypotheses derived from the economic and entrepreneurship literatures about the benefits of in-house versus outside counsel in the unique context of start-up firms.

Darian M. Ibrahim & D. Gordon Smith, Entrepreneurs on Horseback:  Reflections on the Organization of Law, 50 Ariz. L. Rev. 71 (2008).

Abstract (from the introduction): “Law and entrepreneurship” is an emerging field of study. Skeptics might wonder whether law and entrepreneurship is a variant of that old canard, the Law of the Horse. In this Essay, we defend law and entrepreneurship against that charge and urge legal scholars to become even more engaged in the wide-ranging scholarly discourse regarding entrepreneurship. In making our case, we argue that research at the intersection of entrepreneurship and law is distinctive. In some instances, legal rules and practices are tailored to the entrepreneurial context, and in other instances, general rules of law find novel expression in the entrepreneurial context. As a result, studying connections between law and entrepreneurship offers unique insights about them both.

Susan R. Jones, A Legal Guide to Microenterprise Development, 2004 Amer. Bar Ass’n Sec. Bus. L. Pub.

Abstract: Addresses microenterprise and seeks to offer guidance to lawyers who volunteer to represent microentrepreneurs and microenterprise development organizations that facilitate the development of these small businesses. The aspects covered in this manual include: how lawyers can get involved in microenterprise; guidelines on legal formation issues and business issues for microbusinesses; setting up microenterprise programs; information on organizations that support microenterprise and assistance provided by federal agencies. The manual also includes a workbook containing sample loan documents and other resources.

Teemu Kautonen, Do Age-Related Social Expectations Influence Entrepreneurial Activity in Later Life? 13 Int’l J. Entrepren. & Innovation 179 (2012), available athttp://ssrn.com/abstract=2271627.

 Abstract (by author): This article examines how the social expectations of the general public concerning the economic contribution of older people (country-level explanatory variable) affect the entrepreneurial activity of ageing individuals (individual-level dependent variable). A multilevel analysis based on data from 24 European countries finds that the perceived economic contribution of older people is negatively associated with entrepreneurial activity at an older age. The article suggests that the negative effect may be due to a higher perceived economic contribution of ageing people leading to less ageism in the workplace and higher demand for older workers in the labour market, which undermines the relative attractiveness of starting a business.

Lisa A. Kloppenberg, Educating Problem Solving Lawyers for Our Professions and Communities, 61 Rutgers L. Rev. 1099 (2008-2009).

Abstract:  The University of Dayton School of Law began to offer the “Lawyer as Problem Solver” curriculum in 2005. This essay describes our comprehensive curricular revision, aimed at producing problem-solving graduates who are well prepared for practice and leadership in the legal profession and their communities, aligned with the University’s Catholic and Marianist mission of educating “the whole person.” Building on a tradition of experiential learning at Dayton, the curriculum integrates skills more comprehensively, provides practice-related tracks or concentrations in three broad subject areas, and offers an accelerated option that allows students to graduate in as little as two calendar years. The curricular package includes features to attract highly motivated students and provide them with a rigorous, engaging educational experience, including a required externship and a required clinical or capstone experience modeled on the realities of modern legal practice.
Jeffrey M. Lipshaw, Why the Law of Entrepreneurship Barely Matters, 31 W. New Eng. L. Rev. 701 (2009).

Frederick W. Lambert, A Preliminary Inquiry Into the Transcendence of Value Creation, 74 Or. L. Rev. 121 (1995).

Abstract: A consideration of value creation as it influences lawyer and client conduct beyond the confines of the business transaction may be a digression from the stated purpose of the Symposium. But considering the outlying and less immediate and observable consequences of what lawyers do for business clients will illuminate how value is added or subtracted in the business transaction by the sometimes conflicting institutional forces bearing on lawyers in business practice, particularly those in large firms. The preliminary thesis advanced by this essay is as follows: value creation constitutes a medium connecting the economic activity of lawyers with the structure of their organizations, and ultimately influences noneconomic values such as collegiality, solidarity, professionalism and independence - each apparently in decline.

Amir N. Licht, The Entrepreneurial Spirit and What the Law Can Do About It, 28 Comp. Lab. L. & Pol'y J. 817 (2007).

Abstract: Fostering entrepreneurship has become a central policy goal for economic institutions around the world, ranging from regional to national to international bodies. Underlying this trend is the belief that entrepreneurship is key for a number of desirable social outcomes, including economic growth, lower unemployment, and technological modernization. This paper therefore asks a simple and at the same time crucial question: What makes some people more entrepreneurial than others? A companion question follows almost immediately: Can policy-makers do something to promote entrepreneurship?

Emile Loza, Female Entrepreneurship Theory: A Multidisciplinary Review of Resources (Journal of Women's Entrepreneurship and Education, Institute of Economic Sciences, Belgrade, Serbia, 2011), available athttp://ssrn.com/abstract=1833385.

Abstract (adapted from author): This article reviews academic literature regarding and otherwise relevant to the study of female entrepreneurship from across multiple disciplines. The author reports that the legal academy has only minimally engaged in entrepreneurship scholarship and not at all as to female entrepreneurship. The author reviews the origins of female entrepreneurship literature and the compilations describing the emergence of female entrepreneurship as a business and social phenomenon, the women who undertook and led these endeavors, and changes in the characteristics of women entrepreneurs over time. The author also presents materials in topical sections on business structure, strategy, and performance; culture, sex, and gender; diversity; economic and social development; essentialization and masculine norms; finance; identity issues; innovation and technology; motivation; personal and professional domains; psychology; social capital; and standpoint theory. She also points out the needs for a unified definitional taxonomy for entrepreneurship; for greater study of innovation-driven entrepreneurship, including as an endeavor of women; for the legal academy to enter the field of entrepreneurship study, including as to female entrepreneurship, to develop a new substantive area of law; and for entrepreneurship scholars to approach their work with interdisciplinarity.

Paolo Di Martino, Legal Institutions, Social Norms, and Entrepreneurship in Britain (c.1890–c.1939), 55 Acad. Mgmt. J. 35 (2012).

Abstract (from journal): This article analyses the functioning of debt-discharge procedures in England and Wales in the light of the debate on entrepreneurial failure in the years between the late Victorian age and the interwar period. Using an original dataset and an empirical approach, it is argued that social norms, cultural elements, and class considerations influenced the outcome of decisions in a way that could have reduced the incentives for economic agents to engage with productive activity. Results show that over the entire period judges paid disproportionate attention to moral issues, and often gave lighter sentences to members of the elite who went into bankruptcy for personal reasons, and tougher ones to entrepreneurs who failed because of engagement with economic activity.

Benjamin Means, Foreword: A Lens for Law and Entrepreneurship, 6 Ohio St. Entrepren. Bus. L.J. 1 (2011).

Abstract (from author): In this Foreword, the author affirms the value of legal scholarship concerning entrepreneurship but question whether law and entrepreneurship is a “field” in that it involves a “discrete factual setting [that] generates the need for distinctive legal solutions.” First, there is the problem of identifying the relevant factual setting-what is entrepreneurship? Perhaps entrepreneurship is simply the output of individual “entrepreneurs-people with the ideas, the vision, and the perseverance to launch . . . new businesses.” If so, then law and entrepreneurship concerns the legal needs of small, startup business ventures.... Instead of debating the boundaries of law and entrepreneurship as a field, the author uses the metaphor of a lens to contend that law and entrepreneurship should be understood more as a perspective than as a subject of inquiry. Law and entrepreneurship scholars need not restrict their focus to small-business creation and can explore how law and innovation relate in a wide variety of contexts.

Thomas H. Morsch, Discovering Transactional Pro Bono, 72 UMKC  L. Rev. 423 (2003).

Abstract: Lawyers who have spent most of their professional careers in tax, corporate, real estate or business law have long felt that it is difficult for them to make the same pro bono contributions as lawyers who specialize in trial work. In recent years, the situation has changed dramatically.

Charles R. T. O’Kelley, Coase, Knight, and the Nexus-of-Contracts Theory of the Firm: A Reflection of Reification, Reality, and the Corporation as Entrepreneur Surrogate, 35 Seattle U. L. Rev. 1247 (2012).

 Abstract (adapted from author): Scholars routinely credit R. H. Coase and his first seminal work -- The Nature of the Firm -- as the progenitor of the nexus-of-contracts theory of the corporation. This articles argues for a different understanding of Coase's theory of the firm and its implications for legal research into the nature of the modern corporation. An argument is made that nexus-of-contracts scholars' claims to Coase's lineage are based on a misapplication of Coase's central insights and the pursuit of a very different research project that underlayThe Nature of the Firm. Coase's insights must be understood as an extension of Frank Knight's grand opus -- Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit -- and as an extension of Knight's theory of the entrepreneur. This article takes a fresh look at the evolution of the theory of the firm and then details how a new account of the incorporated firm is warranted. The article outlines the research agenda that dominated mainstream economic accounts of the firm prior to Knight and Coase and sketches Knight's seminal account of the entrepreneur. Coase's theory of the firm is described, placing it in the context of Knight's earlier work and highlighting Coase's important identification of the law's place in a real world theory of the firm. The article also explores the implications of Coase's seminal insights for corporation law scholars working on understanding the modern corporation and the theory of the corporation that Coase's work suggests for that work.

David E. Pozen, We Are All Entrepreneurs Now, 43 Wake Forest L. Rev. 283 (2008).

Abstract (from author): A funny thing happened to the entrepreneur in legal, business, and social science scholarship. She strayed from her capitalist roots, took on more and more functions that have little to do with starting or running a business, and became wildly popular in the process. Nowadays, "social entrepreneurs" tackle civic problems through innovative methods, "policy entrepreneurs" promote new forms of government action, "norm entrepreneurs" seek to change the way society thinks or behaves, and "moral entrepreneurs" try to alter the boundaries of duty or compassion. "Ethnification entrepreneurs," "polarization entrepreneurs," and other newfangled spinoffs pursue more discrete objectives. Entrepreneurial rhetoric has never been so trendy or so plastic. This Article documents the proliferation of entrepreneurs in the American academic idiom, and it offers some reflections on the causes and consequences of this trend.

Dana Brakman Reiser, Theorizing Forms for Social Enterprise, 62 Emory L.J. 681 (2013).

Abstract (by author): Jurisdictions across the country and around the globe are enacting legislation enabling founders of social enterprises to adopt specialized forms to house their entities. These forms blend elements traditionally found in nonprofit organizational forms, such as commitment to a social mission, with elements from for-profit business structures, such as the ability to attract investors. These legal forms appear to offer founders and investors the ability to “do well by doing good” and give consumers and employees access to “companies with a soul.” These aspirations, however, have not yet been fully realized by any of the specialized forms currently available. In other work, the author has described and critiqued the specifics of the various new forms, both here and abroad. This Article takes a step back, and examines the broader theoretical question of what specialized forms would have to provide in order for them to help social enterprise to realize its claimed potential.

Rebecca Sandefur & Jeffrey Selbin, The Clinic Effect, 16 Clinical L. Rev. 57 (2009).

Abstract:  Lawyers, law professors and experts on professional education perennially proclaim that law schools teach students to think like lawyers but not to act like them. Legal education’s emphasis in the cognitive dimension comes at the expense of critical professional development in the skills (expertise) and civic (identity) dimensions. Clinical legal education has long been prescribed as a pedagogic corrective to these perceived deficits in law school training, but little research exists to inform our understanding of whether - much less how, when, why and for whom - clinics deliver on this promise. With data from a new, nationally representative survey of early-career attorneys in the United States, this Article explores evidence of clinical education’s impact in the skills and civic dimensions of lawyer training. In the skills dimension, new lawyers rate clinical training more highly for making the transition to the actual practice of law than many other law school experiences, particularly the doctrinal core frequently the object of the standard critique. In the civic dimension, the study finds no evidence of a relationship between clinical training experiences and new lawyers’ pro bono service, and no consistent evidence of a relationship between clinical training experiences and new lawyers’ civic participation. Although there is no evidence of a general relationship between clinical training experiences and public service employment, the study finds a strong relationship between clinical training and career choice for those young attorneys who recall that they came into law hoping to improve society or help individuals. For this group of new lawyers, clinical training may have been an important factor in sustaining or accelerating their original civic commitments. As a result of these findings and the continued dearth of data on these important questions, the Article concludes with a call for a new generation of research into the effects of clinical legal education on the preparation of students for the practice and profession of law.

Karol Ĺšledzik, Schumpeter’s View on Innovation and Entrepreneurship (2013),available athttp://ssrn.com/abstract=2257783.

 Abstract (by author): We are living in a complex and dynamic world in which innovation and entrepreneurship occupy a decisive role for economic development. According to Joseph Alois Schumpeter “carrying out innovations is the only function which is fundamental in history.” He also stressed that it is entrepreneurship that “replaces today’s Pareto optimum with tomorrow’s different new thing.” Schumpeter's words that entrepreneurship is innovation have never seemed so appropriate, when modern capitalism is experiencing a serious crisis and has lost its strength during the last subprime and euro-debt crises. The purpose of this paper is to analyze Schumpeter’s innovation concept in a context of “first” and “second” entrepreneurship theory.

D. Gordon Smith & Darian M. Ibrahim, Law and Entrepreneurial Opportunities, 98 Cornell Law Review, Vol. 98 (forthcoming 2013), available athttp://ssrn.com/abstract=2220075.

Abstract (by authors): 'Opportunity' is a central concept in entrepreneurship research, and this Article explores the relationship between law and entrepreneurial opportunities. The authors adopt the widely held view that entrepreneurial opportunities are ideas created by entrepreneurs, rather than resources waiting to be discovered. Of course, as with all products of the imagination, entrepreneurial opportunities draw on existing resources for inspiration, and we contend that some legal systems are better than other legal systems at encouraging entrepreneurs to think about existing resources in new ways. The authors also contend that when entrepreneurial opportunities are exploited, the inventory of resources expands, thus laying the foundation for the creation of more entrepreneurial opportunities. This 'opportunity cycle' leads to plentiful and continuous opportunity creation. Legal rules play an important role in each stage in the opportunity cycle, and two sets of stories told about law are foundational to innovation research. The first is that property rights (i.e., rights to exclude) are essential in the development of innovative resources because property rights assure market participants that they can retain many of the benefits of their success. The second is that various sets of legal rules – including laws limiting barriers to entry, bankruptcy laws, and corporate laws relating to limited liability and asset partitioning – reduce the costs of entrepreneurial action and failure, thus emboldening entrepreneurs to exploit opportunities. Our thesis is that all of these stories are part of a grander tale about the opportunity cycle, and the central theme of that tale is that the promotion of entrepreneurial action is a fundamental value of the U.S. legal system, the expression of which through positive law inspires entrepreneurs to create more opportunities.

D. Gordon Smith & Darian M. Ibrahim, Law and Entrepreneurial Opportunities, 98 Cornell L. Rev. 1533 (2013).

Abstract (adapted from authors): In this article, the authors begin by reviewing the existing literature on entrepreneurial opportunities. Entrepreneurial opportunities have an objective component, which leads some commentators to assert that entrepreneurial opportunities are discovered. Nevertheless, the authors join the vast majority of entrepreneurship scholars in concluding that it is the subjective acts of the entrepreneur that mostly create entrepreneurial opportunities. Next, the authors examine how entrepreneurs create opportunities and recognize the sources of novelty or innovation in entrepreneurial opportunities. They review briefly the vast psychology literature on creativity and innovation, which holds that new opportunities have their genesis in existing resources.

Relying on the theory of creative cognition, the authors maintain that entrepreneurs draw on existing resources, their life experiences, and other available ideas in using the processes of analogy, conceptual combination, and abstraction to create entrepreneurial opportunities.  Finally, the authors argue that a legal system can facilitate the creation of entrepreneurial opportunities by emboldening entrepreneurs to act. A legal system encourages entrepreneurial action by assuring entrepreneurs that they can retain the benefits of their success while reducing the costs of their failure. Here the authors draw on Willard Hurst, who discussed how nineteenth-century legal policy in the United States facilitated the “release of individual creative energy” through transacting. Encouraging entrepreneurs to act and release their creative energy results in the pursuit of many ideas, and it is this combination of acting and having existing ideas to act upon that leads to the development of an opportunity cycle that sustains an entrepreneurial society.

Friederike Welter, All You Need Is Trust? A Critical Review of the Trust and Entrepreneurship Literature, 30 Int'l Small Bus. J. 193 (2012).

Abstract (adapted from journal): This article critically reviews the literature pertaining to trust and entrepreneurship, highlighting the diversity and complexity of this construct. In addition, the interdependency of trust with context, as well as its dual nature in relation to control and as a sanctioning mechanism, is explored. Trust can be both a dispositional and a behavioural outcome; ‘genuine’ (personal) trust, sanctions and control coexist and co-evolve within and across different contexts. Trust influences entrepreneurship, not always positively, but entrepreneurial behaviour also has an impact on levels of personal and institutional trust. Future studies of trust and entrepreneurship need to acknowledge the bright and dark sides of trust, its duality and the different contexts in which it occurs. Ultimately, one needs to develop a far more critical analysis of the importance and role of trust in the context of entrepreneurship.

Filter by Author & Category

 

Search all Resources

The information appearing on the EshipLaw Site located at www.eshiplaw.org, including articles and other posted materials, and other resources to which links or citations are provided on the EshipLaw Site is being offered solely for educational purposes, and does not in any way substitute for advice and representation by a licensed attorney. Use of the EshipLaw Site does not create an attorney-client relationship with either the editors, creators or reviewers of the educational content presented on the EshipLaw Site.